DEMAPP07

Solve Cournot oligopoly model via collocation

To illustrate implementation of the collocation method for implicit function problems, consider the example of Cournot oligopoly. In the standard microeconomic model of the firm, the firm maximizes profit by equating marginal revenue to marginal cost (MC). An oligopolistic firm, recognizing that its actions affect price, takes the marginal revenue to be $p + q\frac{dp}{dq}$, where $p$ is price, $q$ is quantity produced, and $\frac{dp}{dq}$ is the marginal impact of output on market price. The Cournot assumption is that the firm acts as if any change in its output will be unmatched by its competitors. This implies that

\begin{equation} \frac{dp}{dq} = \frac{1}{D'(p)} \end{equation}

where $D(p)$ is the market demand curve.

Suppose we wish to derive the effective supply function for the firm, which specifies the quantity $q = S(p)$ it will supply at any price. The firm's effective supply function is characterized by the functional equation

\begin{equation} p + \frac{S(p)}{D'(p)} - MC(S(p)) = 0 \end{equation}

for all positive prices $p$. In simple cases, this function can be found explicitly. However, in more complicated cases, no explicit solution exists.

In [1]:
from demos.setup import np, plt, demo
from compecon import BasisChebyshev, NLP, nodeunif
%matplotlib inline
C:\Anaconda3\lib\site-packages\matplotlib\__init__.py:872: UserWarning: axes.color_cycle is deprecated and replaced with axes.prop_cycle; please use the latter.
  warnings.warn(self.msg_depr % (key, alt_key))

Model parameters

Here, the demand elasticity and the marginal cost function parameter are

In [2]:
alpha = 1.0
eta = 3.5

Approximation structure

A degree-25 Chebychev basis on the interval [0.5, 3.0] is selected; also, the associated collocation nodes p are computed.

In [3]:
n =  21
a = 0.5
b = 2.0

S = BasisChebyshev(n, a, b, labels=['price'], l=['supply'])
p = S.nodes

Residual function

Suppose, for example, that

\begin{equation} D(p) = p^{-\eta} \quad\text{and}\quad MC(q) = \alpha\sqrt{q} + q^2 \end{equation}

Then the functional equation to be solved for S(p),

\begin{equation} \left[p - \frac{S(p)p^{\eta+1}}{\eta}\right] -\left[\alpha\sqrt{S(p)} + S(p)^2\right] = 0 \end{equation}

has no known closed-form solution.

In [4]:
def resid(c):
    S.c = c  # update interpolation coefficients
    q = S(p) # compute quantity supplied at price nodes
    return p - q * (p ** (eta+1) / eta) - alpha * np.sqrt(q) - q ** 2

Notice that resid only takes one argument. The other parameters (Q, p, eta, alpha) should be declared as such in the main script, were Python's scoping rules will find them.

Solve for effective supply function

Class NLP defines nonlinear problems. It can be used to solve resid by Broyden's method.

In [5]:
c0 = np.zeros(n)  # set initial guess for coefficients
c0[0] = 1
cournot = NLP(resid)
S.c = cournot.broyden(c0, tol=1e-12)

Plot demand and effective supply for m=5 firms

In [6]:
pplot = nodeunif(501, a, b)
splot = S(pplot)
dplot = pplot ** -eta
demo.figure('Cournot Effective Firm Supply Function', 
            'Quantity', 'Price', [0, 4], [0.5, 2])
plt.plot(5 * splot, pplot, dplot, pplot)
plt.legend(('Supply','Demand'))
Out[6]:
<matplotlib.legend.Legend at 0x1f958190898>

Plot residual

Notice that resid does not take explicit parameters, so to evaluate it when prices are pplot we need to assign p = pplot.

In order to assess the quality of the approximation, one plots the residual function over the approximation domain. Here, the residual function is plotted by computing the residual at a refined grid of 501 equally spaced points.

In [7]:
p = pplot 
rplot = resid(S.c)
demo.figure('Residual Function for Cournot Problem',
            'Quantity', 'Residual')
plt.hlines(0, a, b, 'k', '--', lw=2)
plt.plot(pplot, rplot)
Out[7]:
[<matplotlib.lines.Line2D at 0x1f95825b438>]

Plot demand and effective supply for m=1, 3, 5, 10, 15, 20 firms

In [8]:
m = np.array([1, 3, 5, 10, 15, 20])
demo.figure('Industry Supply and Demand Functions', 
            'Quantity', 'Price', [0, 13])
plt.plot(np.outer(splot, m), pplot, dplot, pplot)
plt.legend(['m=1', 'm=3', 'm=5', 'm=10', 'm=15', 'm=20'])
Out[8]:
<matplotlib.legend.Legend at 0x1f9582cae10>

Plot equilibrium price as a function of number of firms m

In [9]:
pp = (b + a) / 2
dp = (b - a) / 2
m  = np.arange(1, 26)
for i in range(50):
    dp /= 2
    pp = pp - np.sign(S(pp) * m - pp ** (-eta)) * dp

demo.figure('Cournot Equilibrium Price as Function of Industry Size', 
            'Number of Firms', 'Price')
plt.plot(m, pp)
Out[9]:
[<matplotlib.lines.Line2D at 0x1f9582f6ac8>]